000 | 01926nas a2200253Ia 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
008 | 240802c99999999xx |||||||||||| ||und|| | ||
022 | _a0895-3309 | ||
100 |
_aBarlevy, Gadi _9120011 |
||
245 | 4 | _aThe Shifting Reasons for Beveridge Curve Shifts | |
260 | _bJournal of Economic Perspectives | ||
260 | _c2024 | ||
300 | _a83-106 | ||
520 | _aWe discuss how the relative importance of factors that contribute to movements of the US Beveridge curve has changed from 1959 to 2023. We review these factors in the context of a simple flow analogy used to capture the main insights of search and matching theories of the labor market. Changes in inflow rates, related to demographics, accounted for Beveridge curve shifts between 1959 and 2000. A reduction in matching efficiency, that depressed unemployment outflows, shifted the curve outwards in the wake of the Great Recession. In contrast, the most recent shifts in the Beveridge curve appear driven by changes in the eagerness of workers to switch jobs. Finally, we argue that, while the Beveridge curve is a useful tool for relating unemployment and job openings to inflation, the link between these labor market indicators and inflation depends on whether and why the Beveridge curve shifted. Therefore, a careful examination of the factors underlying movements in the Beveridge curve is essential for drawing policy conclusions from the joint behavior of unemployment and job openings. | ||
650 |
_a Aggregate Human Capital _9119520 |
||
650 |
_a Aggregate Labor Productivity, Labor Demand, Labor Turnover _9120012 |
||
650 |
_a Employment _9186 |
||
650 |
_a Intergenerational Income Distribution _9119523 |
||
650 | _a Wages | ||
650 |
_aUnemployment _93282 |
||
700 |
_a Faberman, R. Jason _9120013 |
||
700 |
_a Hobijn, Bart _9120014 |
||
700 |
_aAysegul Sahin _9120015 |
||
856 | _uhttps://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jep.38.2.83 | ||
999 |
_c133611 _d133611 |